Zeqian Li is a postgraduate student under the tutelage of Prof. Lijun Bo at the School of Mathematical Sciences, University of Science and Technology of China. His research mainly focuses on mean-field analysis
This paper considers an n-particle jump-diffusion system with mean filed interaction, where the coefficients are locally Lipschitz continuous. We address the convergence as n→∞ of the empirical measure of the jump-diffusions to the solution of a deterministic McKean–Vlasov equation. The strong well-posedness of the associated McKean–Vlasov equation and a corresponding propagation of chaos result are proven. In particular, we also provide precise estimates of the convergence speed with respect to a Wasserstein-like metric.
Graphical Abstract
An estimate on the speed of the convergence of the empirical measure to the limit measure is given with respect to a Wasserstein-like distance.
Abstract
This paper considers an n-particle jump-diffusion system with mean filed interaction, where the coefficients are locally Lipschitz continuous. We address the convergence as n→∞ of the empirical measure of the jump-diffusions to the solution of a deterministic McKean–Vlasov equation. The strong well-posedness of the associated McKean–Vlasov equation and a corresponding propagation of chaos result are proven. In particular, we also provide precise estimates of the convergence speed with respect to a Wasserstein-like metric.
Public Summary
Constructing the n-particle system with mean filed interaction, whose dynamic follows a couple of SDEs with jumps.
Studying the existence of a solution to the corresponding McKean-Vlasov limit equation.
Establishing the propagation of chaos under a proper metric, giving an estimate of the speed of the convergence and proving the uniqueness of the solution to the McKean-Vlasov limit equation.
As the global economic recession and social focus on sustainability began, consumers and society began to explore more effective uses of resources and products. In recent years, progress on the Internet and mobile communication technology has made large-scale collaborative consumption possible[1-2]. The sharing economy is making changes in various industries, and emerging sharing companies, such as Airbnb and Uber, have made the sharing economy popular[3-5]. The sharing of products or services has developed rapidly in the past few years. It is estimated that global revenues of the sharing market have the potential to reach approximately 335billionby2025from15 billion now[6]. That is, the sharing economy has huge prospects.
In traditional sharing (peer-to-peer sharing market), product sharing occurs between consumers[7]. Although it provides convenience for consumers, original equipment manufacturers (OEMs) may suffer from a decrease in sales caused by the loss of some potential consumers. For example, new car ownership fell by 5% when Getaround built the car peer-to-peer sharing platform[8]. Similarly, in housing rental, the hotel room revenue is estimated to have fallen by 10% in the past five years due to Airbnb in Austin, Texas[9].
Faced with the emergence of the sharing economy, some traditional manufacturers are taking a certain strategy to cope with the sharing economy; for example, some traditional automobile manufacturers have provided product sharing. Some of them choose to rent products to consumers through their own sharing platform[10]. For instance, BMW and Daimler have launched ReachNow① and Car2go②, respectively. In reality, a self-built platform restricts consumers from renting products in many ways, including small scale and little service experience, leading to inconvenient and costly rental service[11]. As a result, many manufacturers actively cooperate with third-party B2C platforms, which charge a certain commission fee for helping OEMs rent out products. For example, JIA BEI, a third-party B2C car-sharing platform, provides operations and maintenance of car-sharing and charges OEMs commission fees③. Compared with a self-built platform, a third-party sharing platform is more feasible for most OEMs.
In this paper, we focus on the OEMs’ sharing of products and examine how product sharing with a third-party platform affects competing manufacturers’ entry and pricing strategies. Taking automobiles as an example, there are many OEMs in the market, but some of them cooperate with the sharing platform, such as Buick providing electric vehicles for Evcard④, while others do not. How do they make the choice? A few papers researched the B2C sharing model[12-14], and they considered only one OEM in the market, without competition factors. However, the impact of product sharing on competing OEMs is still unclear. Based on previous studies, we research the B2C sharing model in a competing environment. We aim to research the following questions in a competitive environment: (i) Under what conditions are consumers willing to rent products? (ii) How does product sharing affect different manufacturers’ entry and pricing strategies?
We develop an analytical framework consisting of two manufacturers and a sharing platform to study how product sharing affects competing manufacturers. In the model, two OEMs produce alternative products with different qualities and sell them to consumers directly. When a third-party B2C sharing platform enters the market, OEMs can rent out products through the platform and pay a certain commission fee. According to different participants in sharing, we discuss two modes of B2C sharing, in which game theory is applied to research the competing OEMs’ pricing strategies and then provide certain suggestions for manufacturers’ entry strategies.
We contribute to the literature by exploring the B2C sharing model from the perspective of competing manufacturers. First, the conditions under which consumers are willing to rent products are identified. When the high-quality OEM cooperates with the third-party sharing platform, if the perceived quality of renting high-quality products is greater than that of purchasing low-quality products, consumers are willing to rent only if the use frequency and rental price are low. Otherwise, consumers are willing to rent only if the rental price is low enough. Moreover, when the low-quality OEM cooperates with the sharing platform, rental demand exists only when the rental price is low, and this rental price is much lower than in the former case.
Furthermore, we analyze the effect of product sharing on manufacturers’ entry and pricing strategies. On the one hand, when the high-quality OEM cooperates with the third-party sharing platform, the high-quality OEM will benefit only if the rental price is moderate, and it should enter the sharing market at this time in the situation that the perceived quality of renting high-quality product is greater than that of purchasing low-quality product. However, the profit of a low-quality OEM is greater only with a high rental price. If the perceived quality of rental high quality is less than that of purchasing low quality product, the profits of both OEMs will be lower; accordingly, the high-quality OEM should not join in the sharing. The high-quality OEM is suggested to maintain a quality advantage if it enters the sharing market. On the other hand, when the low-quality OEM cooperates with the third-party sharing platform, it should share when the rental price is moderate. However, the profit of a high-quality OEM is higher only if the rental price is low. It deduces that the low-quality OEM has more interest in offering product sharing if the perceived quality of renting high-quality product is smaller than that of purchasing low-quality product.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. The related works are summarized in Section 2. In Section 3, we describe the model in detail, and in Section 4, we give the equilibrium results and conditions under which consumers are willing to rent. Through analysis, we show the effect of product sharing on OEMs’ entry and pricing strategies in Section 5. Finally, we summarize the conclusions, limitations and future research directions of this study in Section 6.
2.
Literature review
In the sharing economy, we study the entry strategies and pricing decisions of competing manufacturers. In this section, we review the literature related to sharing platforms and their impact on traditional manufacturers of product sharing.
2.1
Operations management of sharing platforms
The literature on the operation decisions of sharing platforms is extensive[15, 16]. Many studies focus on the service design and resource allocation of sharing platforms. Through trading off customer satisfaction against operation costs, He et al.[17] studied how to design a geographical service region for service providers to operate their service. Some car-sharing platforms, such as Uber or DiDi, provide pooled rides for customers, for which Jacob and Roet-Green[18] designed price-service menus and identified when the platform should offer ride-sharing services. Due to rapid expansion in early times of development, some platforms, such as ofo bicycles, have large redundancy in allocation. By analyzing platform companies’ operations in China’s sharing market, Xu et al.[19] proposed three main mechanisms for sharing economy platforms to coordinate external resources.
Many scholars study sharing platforms from an operational perspective. There are many practices on P2P sharing in the fashion industry. Motivated by this, Choi and He[20] employed stylized models and conducted empirical analysis in their research. It is proven that the platform should adopt the revenue sharing scheme rather than a fixed service fee scheme. However, Hu and Zhou[21] pointed out that the on-demand matching platform may prefer a fixed commission because of the simplicity of communication with independent contractors. Benjaafar et al.[22, 23] examined a sharing platform maximizing either profit or welfare in P2P and ride sharing, respectively. Likewise, focusing on prices and subsidies, Fang et al.[24] attempted to find the optimal prices of sharing platforms in revenue maximization and social welfare maximization. They show that supply shortages may lead to sharing platforms’ limited profitability. Accordingly, platforms are motivated to encourage sharing via subsidies. Gal-Or[25] examined the effect of competition among peer-to-peer lodging platforms and finds that intensified competition may surprisingly lead to a decline in consumer surplus owing to platforms charging higher fees from peer suppliers. From other perspectives, Bian et al.[26] indicated that the platform company does not always opt to offer the B2C sharing service, which is heavily influenced by the fraction of P2P sharing product owners, the platform firm’s customer approval level, and the related marginal production cost.
2.2
Impact of product sharing on traditional manufacturers
Many scholars research traditional manufacturers’ response to changes in the market situation when the sharing economy emerges[23, 27, 28, 11]. For example, Bellos et al.[29] found that an OEM will improve the comfort of retail cars to raise their price and improve the fuel efficiency of rental vehicles to reduce operating costs when developing its car-sharing business. Roma et al.[30] examined incumbents’ price response to emerging sharing economy platforms (e.g., Airbnb). They show that the influence of the expanding importance of the sharing economy on incumbents’ prices is determined by the type of incumbents, the accommodation time, and the type of customers. Similarly, Dai and Nu[31] investigated the equilibrium price for a capacity-constrained manufacturer using various sharing modes. They discovered that B2C sharing results in a cheaper retail price for low-cost devices with a high limited capacity, creating a win‒win situation for both the maker and the customer.
A set of studies focuses on whether a manufacturer should enter the sharing market and use a P2P or B2C sharing strategy. From the perspectives of ownership and the pooling effect, Yu et al.[32] found that selling items of relatively high (poor) quality in B2C sharing is extremely profitable for product categories with a substantial pooling effect or when firm profits highly from ownership. Tian et al.[28] employed a game-theoretic analytical model to research manufacturers’ participation in the sharing economy, finding that the OEM will not join the product-sharing market at low transaction costs or not at a very high marginal cost of production. In contrast, based on a P2P sharing market, Wang et al.[33] found that only if the share of low-usage users is reasonably high will the traditional manufacturer enter the sharing market. According to the value perception factor and the marginal cost, Li et al.[34] examined the OEM’s decision to collaborate with a third-party B2C platform or a third-party P2P platform. The self-built platform, however, has not been considered. To address this gap, Zhang et al.[11] investigated the effects of several factors, such as the consumers’ inconvenient cost and the marginal cost of production, on the manufacturer’s mode selection of establishing the sharing platform or cooperating with a third-party sharing platform.
The above literature expounds on the challenges and opportunities brought by the sharing economy and studies the impact of the sharing economy on manufacturers. However, they do not consider competing OEMs, which is common in reality. This research contributes to the literature by introducing competitive factors into the sharing market. Focusing on product sharing, we describe the utility of consumers’ choices under various sharing modes from the perspective of consumers’ preference for product quality and then establish a mathematical model using game theory to analyze the pricing decisions and entry strategies of manufacturers in a competitive market.
3.
The model
Consider that there are two duopolistic original equipment manufacturers (OEMs) in the market who produce similar products with different qualities and sell them to customers directly, as shown in mode SN of Fig. 1. Suppose the high-quality OEM (
OEM1) produces high-quality products (product 1) with quality
q1 and retails with price
p1, while the low-quality OEM (
OEM2) produces low-quality products (product 2) with quality
q2 (
q2<q1) and retails with price
p2. Without loss of generality, we normalize the two OEMs’ marginal costs to 0. This setting allows us to focus on the quality competition between the OEMs with clear presentations, and this setting is widely adopted in the literature[35, 36]. One may argue that producing high-quality products will cost more resources, including manpower, materials and financial support. Here, we focus on the marginal costs rather than investments for technology improvements. Therefore, it is reasonable to assume that both OEMs have the same marginal cost.
Each consumer cannot buy or rent more than one unit and can obtain usage value from the product. Consumer j’s per usage value
vj depends on his own quality preference (
θj) and the quality of product i (
qi), which means
vj=θjqi. We use the heterogeneous
θj to describe consumers in the market who have different preferences for product quality, assuming that
θ is uniformly distributed between 0 and 1. The use frequency of consumers is
μ, which refers to the ratio of the time consumers spend using the product to the service life of the product, and we normalize the service life to one.
μ is assumed to be a homogeneous parameter to focus on a certain market, such as the use of bicycles by office workers[37, 34]. Therefore,
μθjqi represents the total usage value for consumer j who buys producti. Without loss of generality, the total number of consumers is supposed to be one.
As shown in Fig. 1, in the sharing economy, OEMs can share products through a third-party sharing platform, which collects commission. According to different participants of sharing, we discuss two modes of B2C sharing (mode SBH and mode SBL). A consumer can either be owner by purchasing from OEM, or be renter by renting from sharing platform. It is noted that the commission rate
α∈(0,1) is given. Different from previous studies in which sharing platforms make price decisions, the sharing price is considered to be exogenous in our research. On the one hand, an exogenous sharing price is in line with reality due to intense rivalry and governmental control⑤. For instance, in January 2018, the BMW 3 Series 2016 White model was priced at $80 both on Car2go and Turo[28]. Furthermore, in China, the number of registered car-sharing firms has topped 1600, and key players, such as Gofun supported by Shou Qi Group and Morefun backed by BAIC Group, utilize similar sharing pricing⑥. On the other hand, an exogenous sharing price is widely adopted in the literature[23, 31]. This setting ensures that our study focuses on manufacturers facing competition. Accordingly, an exogenous sharing price is reasonably adopted in our research.
Consumers can choose to buy product 1, product 2, or an outside choice if there is no sharing in the market (mode SN), as shown in Fig. 1. To describe customer preferences, we employ a utility function. Because the consumer is the owner, he obtains gross usage value positively related to
μ,
θ and
q and just needs to pay the purchase price
pi, which has no relation with use frequency
μ. Considering that the utility of the external option is 0, which means
U0j=0, and
Uoij is given by Eq. (1), where o and j means consumer j buys and owns a product,
i=1 means product 1 and
i=2 means product 2.
Uoij=μθjqi−pi,i=1,2.
(1)
In the B2C sharing model, we discuss the situation where only one OEM works with the sharing platform. Accordingly, there are two sharing modes with different sharing participants. The OEM participating in the B2C sharing market puts its products on the sharing platform, which rents products to consumers at rental price (
r1 or
r2) and only needs to bear a certain maintenance cost. The OEM providing sharing product can earn rental revenue (
(1−α)r1 or
(1−α)r2) per transaction.
β (
0<β<1) is the quality discount coefficient of consumers using rented products, reflecting consumers’ concerns about quality when renting products from the platform.
β is assumed to be homogeneous to focus on a specific platform, which has a fixed service level. For the same product, the perceived quality from purchase will definitely be higher than that of rental owing to the platform’s poor service level and the gap on psychological generated by nonownership. Every time the consumer uses product i, he obtains usage value and pays the rent. Thus, what he pays is related to use frequency
μ.The utility functions of different types of owners (o) and renters (r) are given by Eqs. (1) and (2), respectively.
Urij=μ(θjβqi−ri),i=1,2.
(2)
The following is the sequence of events. In mode SN, the OEMs first set the retail prices, and then consumers make their choices to buy which product. In mode SB, in a specific sharing mode (SBH or SBL), the OEMs choose their retail price in the meantime. Next, consumers make decisions on purchase, rental or outside options.
4.
Analysis
In this section, we analyze the benchmark when there is no sharing economy (mode SN) and then research OEMs’ equilibriums in mode SB. All the detailed analysis processes are presented in the appendix. To make it more understandable, we use subscript “1” (and “2”) to denote the high- (and low-)quality manufacturer and use “o” and “r” for owner and renter. Furthermore, SN\SBH\SBL are used as superscripts to distinguish different modes.
4.1
Benchmark: no sharing mode (SN)
First, the no sharing mode is considered the benchmark case with the OEMs as sellers only. Consumers can choose to buy product 1, product 2 or outside options. According to Eq. (1), the indifference point
θ1=p1−p2μ(q1−q2) is obtained from
Uo1=Uo2. Furthermore, we obtain the thresholds
θ0=p2μq2 through
Uo2⩾0 and
θ0=p1μq1 through
Uo1⩾0. Therefore, we have
Uo1>Uo2 if
θ>θ1;
Uo2>0 if
θ>θ0; and
Uo1>0 if
θ>θ0. After considering all different conditions, the relation is reasonable only when
θ1>θ0>θ0 to ensure that all possible market segments exist. Consumers with
θ∈(θ1,1) prefer product 1 because
Uo1>Uo2>0, while consumers with
θ∈(θ0,
θ1) prefer product 2 because
Uo2>Uo1 and
Uo2>0. Thus, the retail demands for products 1 and 2 are
DSN1=1−θ1 and
DSN2=θ1−θ0, respectively. Accordingly, the manufacturers’ profits are given by
πSN1=p1(1−p1−p2μ(q1−q2)),
πSN2=p2(p1−p2μ(q1−q2)−p2μq2). In the following discussion, we will keep key steps and ignore some details for simplicity because they are similar to this process.
Note that there always exists purchase demand for product 1 and product 2 in mode SN. The OEMs’ optimal pricing and profits are summarized in Lemma 4.1.
Lemma 4.1. When there is no sharing product in the market, the equilibria are as follows.
(1) The high-quality OEM’s optimal retail price is
pSN∗1=2μq1(q1−q2)4q1−q2, the retail demand is
DSN∗1=2q14q1−q2, and the optimal profit is
πSN∗1=4μq21(q1−q2)(4q1−q2)2.
(2) The low-quality OEM’s optimal retail price is
pSN∗2=μq2(q1−q2)4q1−q2, the retail demand is
DSN∗2=q14q1−q2, and the optimal profit is
πSN∗2=μq1q2(q1−q2)(4q1−q2)2.
To earn the most, the OEMs develop their optimal pricing strategy according to Lemma 4.1. Then, consumers make their purchase decisions. Finally, the OEMs make their profits.
4.2
B2C sharing mode (SB)
In this case, it is assumed that only one OEM works with the B2C sharing platform. Therefore, there are two conditions according to different sharing participants: (i) mode SBH: the high-quality OEM enters the sharing market; (ii) mode SBL: the low-quality OEM cooperates enters the sharing market.
4.2.1
The high-quality OEM enters the sharing market (SBH)
Now, we examine when the third-party sharing platform cooperates with the high-quality OEM, consumers can either buy product 1 or product 2 from OEMs directly or rent product 1 on the third-party sharing platform. Several indifference points are obtained,
θ1=p1−p2μ(q1−q2),
θ2=p1−μr1μ(1−β)q1, and
θ3=p2−μr1μ(q2−βq1) from
Uo1=Uo2,
Uo1=Ur1 and
Ur1=Uo2, respectively. We obtain the thresholds
θ4=r1βq1 and
θ0=p2μq2 from
Ur1>0,
Uo2>0.
In the sharing market, rental products compete with retail products. Nevertheless, product 1 is of better quality than product 2 (
q1>q2), and the relationship between the perceived quality of renting product 1 and purchasing product 2 is still unknown due to the quality discount parameter
β. For this reason, we research the SBH mode from two aspects according to the difference between the perceived quality of rental and purchase product, as shown in Fig. 2.
Figure
2.
Possible scenarios of consumer segmentations in mode SBH.
When
βq1>q2, the perceived quality of renting product 1 is higher than that of buying product 2 due to the great quality difference or the large quality discount parameter. According to Fig. 2, with a similar derivation process in the benchmark model, we obtain the demands for product 1 and product 2, respectively:
DSBH1o=1−θ2,
DSBH1r=θ2−θ3 and
DSBH2o=θ3−θ0. Moreover, the profits of the two OEMs can be expressed as follows:
πSBH1=p1(1−p1−μr1μ(1−β)q1)+(1−α)⋅r1(p1−μr1μ(1−β)q1−p2−μr1μ(q2−βq1)),
πSBH2=p2(p2−μr1μ(q2−βq1)−p2μq1).
Similarly, when
βq1<q2, i.e., the perceived quality of renting product 1 is lower than that of buying product 2 to consumers as a result of a small quality difference or small quality discount parameter, the quantities demanded for product 1 and product 2 are as follows:
DSBH1o=1−θ1,
DSBH1r=θ3−θ4 and
DSBH2o=θ1−θ3. The profit expressions of the OEMs are
πSBH1=p1(1−p1−p2μ(q1−q2))+(1−α)r1(p2−μr1μ(q2−βq1)−r1βq1) and
πSBH2=p2(p1−p2μ(q1−q2)−p2−μr1μ(q2−βq1)).
To further study the sharing economy, the conditions are concluded for the existence of rental demand in Proposition 4.1.
Proposition 4.1. When the high-quality OEM works with the B2C sharing platform:
(1) When
βq1>q2, in the domain where
0<u⩽uSBH, or
0<r1<rSBH11 and
uSBH<u<1, consumers willing to rent products exist;
(2) when
βq1<q2, in the domain where
r1<rSBH21, consumers willing to rent products exist;
(3) otherwise, there is no consumer willing to rent products.
The most evident aspect of mode B2C, in comparison to mode SN, is that the sharing product directly competes with retail products. As shown in Fig. 3, consumers are willing to rent in the gray area. First, when
βq1>q2, in the domain of
0<u⩽uSBH, due to consumers’ low usage frequency and the high perceived quality of rental product 1, shared product 1 is particularly appealing to customers. Consequently, there exist consumers willing to rent. However, if consumers have a higher usage frequency (
uSBH<u<1), only product 1 with a low rental price (
0<r1<rSBH11) can attract them. In addition, in the remaining area, consumers only purchase products because of the high use frequency and high rental price. In addition, when
βq1<q2, in the domain of
r1>rSBH21, no consumer is willing to rent product 1 because of the high rental price. Moreover, the feasible region of
r1 in this case is far smaller than the former. This can be explained by the small quality difference and the small quality discount parameter, which means that rental product 1 brings less usage value than retail product 2. Consequently, consumers decline in willingness to pay for rental and willing to rent exist only in the domain of small enough
r1 (
r1<rSBH21) when
βq1<q2.
Figure
3.
Conditions for the existence of rental demand in mode SBH.
In the domain where there exists consumer willing to rent, we can obtain the following equilibria in Lemma 4.2. In the remaining area, it is the same as the SN case, as there is no rental demand.
Lemma 4.2. When the high-quality OEM works with the B2C sharing platform and there exists rental demand, there exists a pair of unique solutions that maximizes the two OEMs’ profits.
Lemma 4.2 shows that OEMs have unique optimal prices leading to the highest profits in the SBH mode. The analysis process is presented in detail in the appendix. We will compare OEMs’ equilibrium profits in modes SBH and SN in Section 5 to further understand the impact of the sharing economy.
4.2.2
The low-quality OEM enters the sharing market (SBL)
In this part, the background is that the low-quality OEM not only sells product 2 to consumers but also shares it through the sharing platform, while the high-quality OEM only retails product 1. Consumers can rent product 2 at
r2 in the sharing market and purchase products directly from the two OEMs. Moreover, the sharing platform charges the low-quality OEM commission for providing shared service and bearing maintenance cost. The indifference points
θ1=p1−p2μ(q1−q2) and
θ6=p2−μr2μ(1−β)q2 are obtained by
Uo1=Uo2 and
Uo2=Ur2. Meanwhile, we obtain
θ7=r2βq2 from
Ur2>0. With a similar derivation process in the benchmark model, the demands for different products are expressed as
DSBL1o=1−θ1,
DSBL2o=θ1−θ6 and
DSBL2r=θ6−θ7. The profit expressions of the OEMs are
πSBL1=p1(1−p1−p2μ(q1−q2)) and
πSBL2=p2(p1−p2μ(q1−q2)−−p2+μr2μ(−1+β)q2)+(1−α)r2(−p2+μr2μ(−1+β)q2−r2βq2), where the high-quality OEM derives its income only from retail and the low-quality OEM from retail and rental. We know that product 1 is of better quality than product 2 (
q1>q2), and the quality discount parameter is smaller than 1. It is clear that
q1>βq2. The conditions under which rental demand exists are summarized in Proposition 4.2.
Proposition 4.2. When the low-quality works with OEM the B2C sharing platform:
(1) In the domain where
r2⩽rSBL2, there exist consumers willing to rent products;
(2) otherwise, there is no consumer willing to rent products.
From Proposition 4.2, it is known that only in the part under
r2⩽rSBL2 exist consumers willing to rent, as shown in the gray area of Fig. 4. When the low-quality OEM shares its product in the market, consumers’ willingness to rent is low because of the low quality of product 2.
Figure
4.
Conditions for the existence of rental demand in mode SBL.
In the domain where
r2⩽rSBL2, we can obtain the following lemma. In the remaining area, it degenerates to mode SN as there is no rental demand.
Lemma 4.3. When the low-quality OEM works with the B2C sharing platform, in the domain of
r2⩽rSBL2, there exists a pair of unique solutions that maximizes the two OEMs’ profits.
Lemma 4.3 shows that OEMs can reach an equilibrium in the sharing market with the participation of the low-quality OEM. More details of the analysis are presented in the appendix. In Section 5, we will analyze OEMs’ equilibrium results in modes SBL and SN to make the impact of the sharing economy more understood.
In this section, we have answered the question: Under what conditions are consumers willing to rent products? Furthermore, there is a question to be answered: Should OEMs enter the sharing market?
5.
Discussion
With the development of the sharing economy, an increasing number of manufacturers choose to cooperate with sharing platforms, and can sharing definitely bring benefits to OEMs? If not, under what environment should OEMs choose to share? In this section, the no sharing mode (mode SN) is used as the basic mode to research OEMs’ entry strategies in the sharing market in a competitive environment. Similarly, it is divided into three parts according to the different sharing participants: (i) mode SBH vs mode SN; (ii) mode SBL vs mode SN; (iii) mode SBH vs mode SBL. To focus on the impact of product sharing, we only study the domains from Section 4, where consumers willing to rent in the SBH and SBL modes exist in the following analysis.
5.1
Mode SBH vs mode SN
We first compare the profits and prices under mode SBH and mode SN. The profit and retail price differences are defined as
ΔπSBHi=πSBH∗i−πSN∗i,
ΔpSBHi=pSBH∗i−pSN∗i,
i=1,2, respectively. Through analysis of the profit difference of the two OEMs under different modes in the two situations, Proposition 5.1 is derived.
Proposition 5.1. When the high-quality OEM works with the B2C sharing platform and there exists rental demand:
(1) When
βq1>q2:
a)
ΔπSBH1>0 if
rSBH31<r1<rSBH41; and
ΔπSBH1⩽0 if
r1⩽rSBH31 or
r1⩾rSBH41.
b)
ΔπSBH2>0 if
r1>rSBH51; and
ΔπSBH2⩽0 if
r1⩽rSBH51.
c)
ΔpSBH1>0 if
r1>rSBH61; and
ΔpSBH1⩽0 if
r1⩽rSBH61.
d)
ΔpSBH2>0 if
r1>rSBH71; and
ΔpSBH2⩽0 if
r1⩽rSBH71.
(2) When
βq1<q2:
a)
ΔπSBH1<0andΔπSBH2<0.
b)
ΔpSBH1<0andΔpSBH2<0.
Note that the profit differences are discussed in the condition with the existence of consumers willing to rent. We set
q1=8.95,
q2=5.54,
u=0.598,
α=0.231, and
β=0.855 (0.5) to draw Fig. 5 (Fig. 6), which helps us comprehend Proposition 5.1 more easily. From the above proposition, it is known that in the SBH mode, product sharing affects the two OEMs in different ways. In the condition when the perceived quality of rental product 1 is larger than that of retail product 2 (
βq1>q2), first, if
r1 is too low (
r1⩽rSBH31), the emergence of rental products will erode the purchasing demand for the retail products. For this reason, the two OEMs have to lower retail prices to reduce the decrease in purchase demand. For the high-quality OEM, its total profit is lower than that in mode SN because the new rental profit cannot completely compensate for the decrease in retail profit. Second, as the rental price increases, the price for product 1 increases significantly, but the demand for retail and rental product 1 is inversely related to the rental price. It induces that if
r1 is in the middle range (
rSBH31<r1<rSBH41), compared to the no-sharing market, the high-quality OEM makes more profits because of the revenue from rental exceeding the reduction in retail revenue. Third, if
r1 is high enough (
r1⩾rSBH41), although the retail price is much higher than that in mode SN, the demand for retail and rental products 1 is relatively low, so the total profit of the high-quality OEM is lower than that in mode SN.
Figure
5.
Impact of sharing in mode SBH (
βq1>q2).
In other words, the high-quality OEM should join the B2C sharing economy if
r1 is in the middle range (
rSBH31<r1<rSBH41), while it should not if
r1 is too low (
r1⩽rSBH31) or too high (
r1⩾rSBH41).
For the low-quality OEM, if
r1 is low (
r1⩽rSBH51), it has to lower its retail price to reduce the decrease in purchase demand but still profits less than when there is no sharing. With
r1 higher (
r1>rSBH51), the demand and price for retail of product 2 will rise, even more than that in mode SN, which leads to greater profit. In summary, the low-quality OEM will be better off if
r1 is high and worse off if
r1 is low.
Additionally, the case is analyzed in detail when the perceived quality of rental product 1 is smaller than that of retail product 2 (
βq1<q2). Compared with the no sharing economy, the equilibrium prices of the two OEMs are lower, and the purchase demand for product 1 is lower. In contrast, the purchase demand for product 2 is positively related to the rental price of product 1 and finally higher than that without a sharing economy. In contrast, the rental demand for product 1 negatively correlates with the rental price. Inevitably, the appearance of rental products results in more competition between the OEMs, causing a price war. Hence, the low-quality OEM is worse off without a doubt because of the large loss of sale. For the high-quality OEM, rental revenue cannot make up for the loss of sale, leading to a decline in total profit compared to when there is no sharing.
In conclusion, if the high-quality OEM decides to join the sharing economy, it needs to maintain the quality advantage to ensure
βq1>q2. Once the quality gap with a low-quality OEM is narrowed, it is likely to enter the trouble of lose‒lose. Under this condition, the low-quality OEM may be better off or worse. If worse, it can improve its product quality to force the high-quality OEM to give up sharing.
5.2
Mode SBL vs mode SN
Moreover, the equilibria of the two manufacturers are compared under mode SBL and mode SN. The profit and price differences are expressed as
ΔπSBLi=πSBL∗i−πSN∗i,
ΔpSBHi=pSBH∗i−pSN∗i,
i=1,2, respectively. After analysis, the results are as shown in Proposition 5.2.
Proposition 5.2. When the low-quality OEM works with the B2C sharing platform and there exists rental demand, the rental price of product 2 affects the two OEMs in different ways:
(1)
ΔπSBL1>0, if
r2>rSBL32; and
ΔπSBL1⩽0 if
r2⩽rSBL32.
(2)
ΔπSBL2>0, if
rSBL42<r2<rSBL52; and
ΔπSBL2⩽0 if
r2⩽rSBL42 or
r2⩾rSBL52.
(3)
ΔpSBL1>0, if
r2>rSBL62; and
ΔpSBL1⩽0 if
r2⩽rSBL62.
(4)
ΔpSBL2>0, if
r2>rSBL72; and
ΔpSBL2⩽0 if
r2⩽rSBL72.
Note that the profit differences are compared under the condition that consumers are willing to rent; otherwise, the profit difference is 0. To observe Proposition 5.2 more intuitively, we draw Fig. 7 by setting
q1=8.95,
q2=5.54,
u=0.598,
α=0.231, and
β=0.855. To begin with the low rental price of product 2, the emergence of rental products erodes the purchase demand for the two products. To reduce the decrease in purchase demand, the OEMs will take the initiative to lower the retail price. For the low-quality OEM, its total profit is less than when there is no sharing, although it can obtain rental revenue that cannot completely compensate for the decrease in retail profit. Second, the demand for purchases and rentals is negatively related to rental prices. Thus, if
r2 is in the middle range (
rSBL32<r2<rSBL42), the rental revenue exceeds the reduction in sales profit, which means that the low-quality OEM makes more profits in the SBL mode than in the SN mode. Third, if
r2 is high enough (
r2⩾rSBL42), although the retail price is higher, the low-quality OEM is worse off, resulting from very little demand for rental and purchase of product 2. To conclude, the low-quality OEM should enter the B2C sharing economy if
r2 is in a middle range (
rSBL32<r2<rSBL42), while it should not if
r2 is too low (
r2⩽rSBL32) or too high (
r2⩾rSBL42).
For the high-quality OEM, when
r2 is low, the manufacturer earns less, although it tries to reduce the decline of purchase demand by price cut. If
r2 is high, the high-quality OEM will be better off because of the increase of the retail demand and retail price compared with the no-sharing market. In summary, the high-quality OEM will be better off if
r2 is high (
r2>rSBL52) and worse off if
r2 is low (
r2⩽rSBL52).
5.3
Mode SBH vs mode SBL
In this part, mode SBH is compared with mode SBL in the condition when there exist consumers willing to rent product 1 and product 2. Considering the complexity of the analytic formula, this part adopts a numerical experiment for analysis. We set
q1=8.95,
q2=5.54,
u=0.598, and
α=0.231. Similarly, our discussion consists of two parts according to the difference between the perceived quality of purchase product 2 and rental product 1.
First,
β is set as 0.855 to satisfy that the perceived quality of rental product 1 is larger than that of purchase product 2 (
βq1>q2), and different entry strategies are illustrated from the manufacturers’ perspective. As shown in Fig. 8a, we can obtain four parts. First, in part Ⅰ,
ΔπSBH1<0 and
ΔπSBL1>0, which implies that the high-quality OEM is better off in the SBL mode and should not offer rental service. In contrast,
ΔπSBH1>0 and
ΔπSBL1<0 in part Ⅱ, which shows that the high-quality OEM should enter the sharing market. In parts Ⅲ and Ⅳ,
ΔπSBL1>0 and
ΔπSBH1>0. In contrast, if
r1 is given, the high-quality OEM is better off in mode SBH when
r2 is high (part Ⅲ) and better off in mode SBL when
r2 is low (part Ⅳ). As above, the high-quality OEM is suggested to enter the sharing market in part Ⅱ and part Ⅳ, that is,
r1 is moderate and
r2 is low.
Figure
8.
OEMs’ profit comparisons in modes SBH and SBL when
βq1>q2.
Four parts can also be observed from Fig. 8b. Similarly,
ΔπSBH2>0 and
ΔπSBL2<0 in part Ⅴ; accordingly, the low-quality OEM should not cooperate with the sharing platform. In part Ⅵ, it is better to offer rental service for the low-quality OEM because
ΔπSBH2<0 and
ΔπSBL2>0. In part Ⅶ and part Ⅷ, the low-quality OEM is better off in modes SBH and SBL, respectively. This happens because if
r2 is given, the low-quality OEM’s profit is positively related to
r1. Consequently, the low-quality OEM should cooperate with the platform when
r2 is moderate and
r1 is low.
From Proposition 5.1, we know that both OEMs are worse off in mode SBH than in mode SN when the perceived quality of rental product 1 is larger than that of purchase product 2 (
βq1<q2), which leads to a low quality-difference or small quality discount parameter. However, there always exists a region such that OEMs are better off in mode SBL than in mode SN, according to Proposition 5.2. Consequently, both OEMs may prefer SBL, which means that only the low-quality OEM is interested in product sharing when
βq1<q2.
6.
Conclusions
The sharing economy is displacing the traditional business mode as the Internet and mobile communication technology advance. Traditional companies provide product sharing in various forms to win back customers. At present, most studies on the decision-making of manufacturers in the sharing economy consider a complete monopoly market, while competition factors in real life have a significant influence. For this purpose, we innovatively add competition factors when considering the impact of the sharing economy on manufacturers. In this paper, we consider a market consisting of a sharing platform and two manufacturers, which produce alternative products of different quality. Furthermore, we propose a new sharing model in which two OEMs compete with each other. Two modes are researched according to different sharing participants. The manufacturer, joining the sharing market, not only sells products but also rents out through the sharing platform, and consumers make decisions on purchase or rental. We address the condition under which there exist consumers with rental willingness and how OEMs make their entry and pricing strategies in product sharing. Our findings are summarized below.
First, in mode SBH, where the high-quality OEM works with the sharing platform, we research two aspects according to the difference between the perceived quality of rental product 1 and retail product 2 because rental products compete with retail products. On the one hand, when the perceived quality of renting product 1 is greater than the perceived quality of purchasing product 2, if use frequency is low or use frequency is high but the rental price is low, consumers with rental willingness exist in the market. On this premise, the high-quality OEM profits less if the rental price of product 1 is too low or too high, resulting from encroachment of the retail market or loss of potential customers. Thus, it is suggested to share when rental prices are moderate. On the other hand, when the perceived quality of renting a high-quality product is lower than the perceived quality of purchasing a low-quality product, consumers are willing to rent only if the rental price is low enough, and this rental price is much lower than in the former case. Under this condition, the profits of both OEMs will be lower; accordingly, the high-quality OEM should not enter the sharing market.
Second, in mode SBH, if the high-quality OEM decides to join the sharing economy, it is suggested to maintain quality advantage because once the quality gap with low-quality OEM is narrowed, it is likely to enter the trouble of lose‒lose. A low-quality OEM may be better off or worse. If worse, it can improve its product quality to force the high-quality OEM to give up sharing.
Third, in mode SBL, where the low-quality OEM works with the sharing platform, there exists no consumer willing to rent only if the rental price is high. Based on this, if the rental price is moderate, the low-quality OEM should enter the sharing market because of higher profit. When compared with mode SBH, we find that the low-quality OEM has more interest in offering product sharing if the perceived quality of renting high-quality product is smaller than that of purchasing low-quality product.
Finally, the retail prices of the OEMs are positively related to rental prices. At the beginning, when the rental price is low, the retail price is lower than when there is no sharing caused by fierce competition. Generally, once the rental price is above a certain value, the retail price in the sharing market is higher than no sharing. Differently, when the perceived quality of renting a high-quality product is lower than the perceived quality of purchasing a low-quality product, the retail prices in mode SBH are always lower than no sharing because the rental price is kept low enough to ensure the existence of consumers willing to rent.
Against the background of the sharing economy, this paper studies the influence of product sharing on the entry and pricing strategies of competing manufacturers and obtains some innovative research results. However, there are still some limitations in this study, and future directions can be expanded. For instance, it is more realistic to consider the heterogeneity of consumers both in quality preference and usage frequency. It would be interesting to research the scenario when both manufacturers enter the sharing market. In addition, we use fixed rental prices to study manufacturers’ operations but do not take platform pricing into account. To research further, the platform’s operation should be included.
Conflict of interest
The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.
Conflict of Interest
The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.
Constructing the n-particle system with mean filed interaction, whose dynamic follows a couple of SDEs with jumps.
Studying the existence of a solution to the corresponding McKean-Vlasov limit equation.
Establishing the propagation of chaos under a proper metric, giving an estimate of the speed of the convergence and proving the uniqueness of the solution to the McKean-Vlasov limit equation.
Dehnen W, Read J I. N-body simulations of gravitational dynamics. The European Physical Journal Plus, 2011, 126: 55. DOI: 10.1140/epjp/i2011-11055-3
[2]
Sirignano J, Spiliopoulos K. Mean field analysis of neural networks: A central limit theorem. Stochastic Processes and Their Applications, 2020, 130 (3): 1820–1852. DOI: 10.1016/j.spa.2019.06.003
[3]
Bolley F, Canizo J A, Carrillo J A. Stochastic mean-field limit: non-Lipschitz forces and swarming. Mathematical Models and Methods in Applied Sciences, 2011, 21 (11): 2179–2210. DOI: 10.1142/s0218202511005702
[4]
Bender M, Heenen P-H, Reinhard P-G. Selfconsistent mean-field models for nuclear structure. Reviews of Modern Physics, 2003, 75 (1): 121–180. DOI: 10.1103/revmodphys.75.121
[5]
Touboul J. Propagation of chaos in neural fields. Annals of Applied Probability, 2014, 24 (3): 1298–1327. DOI: 10.1214/13-aap950
[6]
Delarue F, Inglis J, Rubenthaler S, et al. Particle systems with a singular mean-field self-excitation. Application to neuronal networks. Stochastic Processes and Their Applications, 2015, 125 (6): 2451–2492. DOI: 10.1016/j.spa.2015.01.007
[7]
Bo L, Capponi A. Systemic risk in interbanking networks. SIAM Journal on Financial Mathematics, 2015, 6 (1): 386–424. DOI: 10.1137/130937664
[8]
Liu W, Song Y, Zhai J, et al. Large and moderate deviation principles for McKean–Vlasov SDEs with jumps. Potential Analysis, 2023, 59 (3): 1141–1190. DOI: 10.1007/s11118-022-10005-0
[9]
Guillin A, Liu W, Wu L, et al. Uniform Poincaré and logarithmic Sobolev inequalities for mean field particle systems. The Annals of Applied Probability, 2022, 32 (3): 1590–1614. DOI: 10.1214/21-aap1707
[10]
Kac M. Foundations of kinetic theory. In: Proceedings of the Third Berkeley Symposium on Mathematical Statistics and Probability, Volume 3: Contributions to Astronomy and Physics. Berkeley, Los Angeles, USA: University of California Press, 1956: 171–197.
[11]
Sznitman A S. Topics in propagation of chaos. In: Ecole d'Eté de Probabilités de Saint-Flour XIX—1989. Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer, 1991: 165–251.
[12]
McKean H P. A class of Markov processes associated with nonlinear parabolic equations. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 1966, 56 (6): 1907–1911. DOI: 10.1073/pnas.56.6.1907
[13]
Mishura Y, Veretennikov A. Existence and uniqueness theorems for solutions of McKean–Vlasov stochastic equations. Theory of Probability and Mathematical Statistics, 2020, 103: 59–101. DOI: 10.1090/tpms/1135
[14]
Lacker D. On a strong form of propagation of chaos for McKean–Vlasov equations. Electronic Communications in Probability, 2018, 23: 1–11. DOI: 10.1214/18-ecp150
[15]
Liu W, Wu L, Zhang C. Long-time behaviors of mean-field interacting particle systems related to McKean–Vlasov equations. Communications in Mathematical Physics, 2021, 387 (1): 179–214. DOI: 10.1007/s00220-021-04198-5
[16]
Andreis L, Dai Pra P, Fischer M. McKean–Vlasov limit for interacting systems with simultaneous jumps. Stochastic Analysis and Applications, 2018, 36 (6): 960–995. DOI: 10.1080/07362994.2018.1486202
[17]
Erny X. Well-posedness and propagation of chaos for McKean–Vlasov equations with jumps and locally Lipschitz coefficients. Stochastic Processes and Their Applications, 2022, 150: 192–214. DOI: 10.1016/j.spa.2022.04.012
[18]
Mehri S, Scheutzow M, Stannat W, et al. Propagation of chaos for stochastic spatially structured neuronal networks with delay driven by jump diffusions. The Annals of Applied Probability, 2020, 30 (1): 175–207. DOI: 10.1214/19-aap1499
[19]
Baladron J, Fasoli D, Faugeras O, et al. Mean-field description and propagation of chaos in networks of Hodgkin–Huxley and FitzHugh–Nagumo neurons. The Journal of Mathematical Neuroscience, 2012, 2: 10. DOI: 10.1186/2190-8567-2-10
[20]
Bossy M, Faugeras O, Talay D. Clarification and complement to “Mean-field description and propagation of chaos in networks of Hodgkin–Huxley and FitzHugh–Nagumo neurons”. The Journal of Mathematical Neuroscience, 2015, 5: 19. DOI: 10.1186/s13408-015-0031-8
[21]
Xu L. Uniqueness and propagation of chaos for the Boltzmann equation with moderately soft potentials. The Annals of Applied Probability, 2018, 28 (2): 1136–1189. DOI: 10.1214/17-aap1327
[22]
Bo L, Liao H. Probabilistic analysis of replicator–mutator equations. Advances in Applied Probability, 2022, 54 (1): 167–201. DOI: 10.1017/apr.2021.22
[23]
Ikeda N, Watanabe S. Stochastic Differential Equations and Diffusion Processes. Amsterdam: Elsevier, 2014.
[24]
Luçon E, Stannat W. Mean field limit for disordered diffusions with singular interactions. The Annals of Applied Probability, 2014, 24 (5): 1946–1993. DOI: 10.1214/13-aap968
[25]
Bard Ermentrout G, Terman D H. Mathematical Foundations of Neuroscience. New York: Springer, 2010.
[26]
Hocquet A, Vogler A. Optimal control of mean field equations with monotone coefficients and applications in neuroscience. Applied Mathematics & Optimization, 2021, 84 (2): 1925–1968. DOI: 10.1007/s00245-021-09816-1
[27]
Garroni M G, Menaldi J L. Green Functions for Second Order Parabolic Integro-Differential Problems. New York: Chapman & Hall/CRC, 1992.
[28]
Mandelkern M. Metrization of the one-point compactification. Proceedings of the American Mathematical Society, 1989, 107 (4): 1111–1115. DOI: 10.1090/s0002-9939-1989-0991703-4
[29]
Fournier N, Guillin A. On the rate of convergence in Wasserstein distance of the empirical measure. Probability Theory and Related Fields, 2015, 162: 707–738. DOI: 10.1007/s00440-014-0583-7
[30]
Hardy G H, Littlewood J E, Pólya G. Inequalities. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1952.
[31]
Protter P E. Stochastic Integration and Differential Equations. Berlin: Springer, 2013.
Dehnen W, Read J I. N-body simulations of gravitational dynamics. The European Physical Journal Plus, 2011, 126: 55. DOI: 10.1140/epjp/i2011-11055-3
[2]
Sirignano J, Spiliopoulos K. Mean field analysis of neural networks: A central limit theorem. Stochastic Processes and Their Applications, 2020, 130 (3): 1820–1852. DOI: 10.1016/j.spa.2019.06.003
[3]
Bolley F, Canizo J A, Carrillo J A. Stochastic mean-field limit: non-Lipschitz forces and swarming. Mathematical Models and Methods in Applied Sciences, 2011, 21 (11): 2179–2210. DOI: 10.1142/s0218202511005702
[4]
Bender M, Heenen P-H, Reinhard P-G. Selfconsistent mean-field models for nuclear structure. Reviews of Modern Physics, 2003, 75 (1): 121–180. DOI: 10.1103/revmodphys.75.121
[5]
Touboul J. Propagation of chaos in neural fields. Annals of Applied Probability, 2014, 24 (3): 1298–1327. DOI: 10.1214/13-aap950
[6]
Delarue F, Inglis J, Rubenthaler S, et al. Particle systems with a singular mean-field self-excitation. Application to neuronal networks. Stochastic Processes and Their Applications, 2015, 125 (6): 2451–2492. DOI: 10.1016/j.spa.2015.01.007
[7]
Bo L, Capponi A. Systemic risk in interbanking networks. SIAM Journal on Financial Mathematics, 2015, 6 (1): 386–424. DOI: 10.1137/130937664
[8]
Liu W, Song Y, Zhai J, et al. Large and moderate deviation principles for McKean–Vlasov SDEs with jumps. Potential Analysis, 2023, 59 (3): 1141–1190. DOI: 10.1007/s11118-022-10005-0
[9]
Guillin A, Liu W, Wu L, et al. Uniform Poincaré and logarithmic Sobolev inequalities for mean field particle systems. The Annals of Applied Probability, 2022, 32 (3): 1590–1614. DOI: 10.1214/21-aap1707
[10]
Kac M. Foundations of kinetic theory. In: Proceedings of the Third Berkeley Symposium on Mathematical Statistics and Probability, Volume 3: Contributions to Astronomy and Physics. Berkeley, Los Angeles, USA: University of California Press, 1956: 171–197.
[11]
Sznitman A S. Topics in propagation of chaos. In: Ecole d'Eté de Probabilités de Saint-Flour XIX—1989. Berlin, Heidelberg: Springer, 1991: 165–251.
[12]
McKean H P. A class of Markov processes associated with nonlinear parabolic equations. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 1966, 56 (6): 1907–1911. DOI: 10.1073/pnas.56.6.1907
[13]
Mishura Y, Veretennikov A. Existence and uniqueness theorems for solutions of McKean–Vlasov stochastic equations. Theory of Probability and Mathematical Statistics, 2020, 103: 59–101. DOI: 10.1090/tpms/1135
[14]
Lacker D. On a strong form of propagation of chaos for McKean–Vlasov equations. Electronic Communications in Probability, 2018, 23: 1–11. DOI: 10.1214/18-ecp150
[15]
Liu W, Wu L, Zhang C. Long-time behaviors of mean-field interacting particle systems related to McKean–Vlasov equations. Communications in Mathematical Physics, 2021, 387 (1): 179–214. DOI: 10.1007/s00220-021-04198-5
[16]
Andreis L, Dai Pra P, Fischer M. McKean–Vlasov limit for interacting systems with simultaneous jumps. Stochastic Analysis and Applications, 2018, 36 (6): 960–995. DOI: 10.1080/07362994.2018.1486202
[17]
Erny X. Well-posedness and propagation of chaos for McKean–Vlasov equations with jumps and locally Lipschitz coefficients. Stochastic Processes and Their Applications, 2022, 150: 192–214. DOI: 10.1016/j.spa.2022.04.012
[18]
Mehri S, Scheutzow M, Stannat W, et al. Propagation of chaos for stochastic spatially structured neuronal networks with delay driven by jump diffusions. The Annals of Applied Probability, 2020, 30 (1): 175–207. DOI: 10.1214/19-aap1499
[19]
Baladron J, Fasoli D, Faugeras O, et al. Mean-field description and propagation of chaos in networks of Hodgkin–Huxley and FitzHugh–Nagumo neurons. The Journal of Mathematical Neuroscience, 2012, 2: 10. DOI: 10.1186/2190-8567-2-10
[20]
Bossy M, Faugeras O, Talay D. Clarification and complement to “Mean-field description and propagation of chaos in networks of Hodgkin–Huxley and FitzHugh–Nagumo neurons”. The Journal of Mathematical Neuroscience, 2015, 5: 19. DOI: 10.1186/s13408-015-0031-8
[21]
Xu L. Uniqueness and propagation of chaos for the Boltzmann equation with moderately soft potentials. The Annals of Applied Probability, 2018, 28 (2): 1136–1189. DOI: 10.1214/17-aap1327
[22]
Bo L, Liao H. Probabilistic analysis of replicator–mutator equations. Advances in Applied Probability, 2022, 54 (1): 167–201. DOI: 10.1017/apr.2021.22
[23]
Ikeda N, Watanabe S. Stochastic Differential Equations and Diffusion Processes. Amsterdam: Elsevier, 2014.
[24]
Luçon E, Stannat W. Mean field limit for disordered diffusions with singular interactions. The Annals of Applied Probability, 2014, 24 (5): 1946–1993. DOI: 10.1214/13-aap968
[25]
Bard Ermentrout G, Terman D H. Mathematical Foundations of Neuroscience. New York: Springer, 2010.
[26]
Hocquet A, Vogler A. Optimal control of mean field equations with monotone coefficients and applications in neuroscience. Applied Mathematics & Optimization, 2021, 84 (2): 1925–1968. DOI: 10.1007/s00245-021-09816-1
[27]
Garroni M G, Menaldi J L. Green Functions for Second Order Parabolic Integro-Differential Problems. New York: Chapman & Hall/CRC, 1992.
[28]
Mandelkern M. Metrization of the one-point compactification. Proceedings of the American Mathematical Society, 1989, 107 (4): 1111–1115. DOI: 10.1090/s0002-9939-1989-0991703-4
[29]
Fournier N, Guillin A. On the rate of convergence in Wasserstein distance of the empirical measure. Probability Theory and Related Fields, 2015, 162: 707–738. DOI: 10.1007/s00440-014-0583-7
[30]
Hardy G H, Littlewood J E, Pólya G. Inequalities. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1952.
[31]
Protter P E. Stochastic Integration and Differential Equations. Berlin: Springer, 2013.